翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Hermann Lange
・ Hermann Lattemann
・ Hermann Lause
・ Hermann Lebert
・ Hermann Hankel
・ Hermann Hansen
・ Hermann Hansen Aarsrud
・ Hermann Harms
・ Hermann Harrendorf
・ Hermann Hartmann
・ Hermann Haupt
・ Hermann Hauser
・ Hermann Hauser, Sr.
・ Hermann Heights Monument
・ Hermann Heinrich Becker
Hermann Heinrich Gossen
・ Hermann Heinrich Howaldt
・ Hermann Heinrich Ploss
・ Hermann Heiss
・ Hermann Helgesen
・ Hermann Heller
・ Hermann Heller (legal scholar)
・ Hermann Heller (Swiss politician)
・ Hermann Hellriegel
・ Hermann Helms
・ Hermann Hendrich
・ Hermann Henking
・ Hermann Henselmann
・ Hermann Hesse
・ Hermann Hiltl


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Hermann Heinrich Gossen : ウィキペディア英語版
Hermann Heinrich Gossen

Hermann Heinrich Gossen (7 September 1810 – 13 February 1858) was a Prussian economist who is often regarded as the first to elaborate a general theory of marginal utility.
==Life and work==
Gossen studied in Bonn, then worked in the Prussian administration until retiring in 1847, after which he sold insurance until his death.
Prior to Gossen, a number of theorists, including Gabriel Cramer,〔Cramer, Garbriel; letter of 21 May 1728 to Nicolaus Bernoulli ((excerpted in PDF )).〕 Daniel Bernoulli,〔Bernoulli, Daniel; “Specimen theoriae novae de mensura sortis” in ''Commentarii Academiae Scientiarum Imperialis Petropolitanae'' 5 (1738); reprinted in translation as “Exposition of a new theory on the measurement of risk” in ''Econometrica'' 22 (1954).〕 William Forster Lloyd,〔Lloyd, William Forster; ''Lectures on Population, Value, Poor Laws and Rent'' (1837).〕 Nassau William Senior,〔Senior, Nassau William; ''An Outline of the Science of Political Economy'' (1836).〕 and Jules Dupuit〔Dupuit, Jules; “De la mesure de l’utilité des travaux publics”, ''Annales des ponts et chaussées'', Second series, 8 (1844).〕 had employed or asserted the significance of some notion of marginal utility. But Cramer, Bernoulli, and Dupuit had focussed upon specific problems, Lloyd had not presented any application, and if Senior actually employed to the development of more general theory〔White, Michael V; “Diamonds Are Forever(?): Nassau Senior and Utility Theory” in ''The Manchester School of Economic & Social Studies'' 60 (1992) #1 (March).〕 then he did so in language that caused the application to be missed by most readers.
Gossen's book ''Die Entwickelung der Gesetze des menschlichen Verkehrs, und der daraus fließenden Regeln für menschliches Handeln'' (''The Development of the Laws of Human Intercourse and the Consequent Rules of Human Action''), published in Braunschweig in 1854, very explicitly developed general theoretical implications from a theory of marginal utility, to the extent that William Stanley Jevons (one of the preceptors of the Marginal Revolution) was later to remark that
However, ''Die Entwickelung'' was poorly received, as economic thought in Germany was then dominated by the Historical School and as Gossen wrote it in a dense, heavily mathematical style which was quite unpopular at the time. Although Gossen himself declared that his work was comparable in its significance to the innovations of Copernicus, few others agreed; most copies of the book were destroyed and, today, only a few original copies exist.
In the early 1870s, William Stanley Jevons, Carl Menger, and Leon Walras each reintroduced the theory of marginal utility. During discussions of which of those three had been the first to formulate the theory, a colleague of Jevons discovered a copy of Die Entwicklung. However, the discovery (in 1878) came several years after the three principals in the Marginal Revolution had published their own books, and significant differences with Gossen’s original contributions were overlooked.
A century later (1983) Gossen’s book was translated into English. In his introduction to the book, Nicholas Georgescu Roegen, a prominent American economist (Distinguished Fellow of the American Economics Association), strongly supported Gossen’s vision, which stands in opposition to the neoclassical orthodoxy that utility (satisfaction) is properly identified with consumables in basic (utility) theory rather than consumption activity:
Georgescu-Roegen also extended Gossen’s behavioral formulation by introducing leisure in addition to production and consumption activities.
Gossen was among the first economists to recognize that a centrally planned economy was unworkable:〔See:
*
* 〕
Original: ''" … nur durch Feststellung des Privateigenthums der Maßstab gefunden wird zur Bestimmung der Quantität, welche den Verhältnissen angemessen amZweckmäßigsten von jeden Gegenstand zu produciren ist. Darum würde denn die von Communisten projectirte Centralbehörde zur Vertheilung der verschiedenen Arbeiten und Ihrer Belohnung sehr bald die Erfahrung machen, daß sie sich eine Aufgabe gestellt habe, deren Lösung die Kräfte einzelner Menschen weit übersteigt."''

''Translation:'' " … only through the establishment of private property is to be found the measure for determining the quantity of each commodity which it would be best to produce under given conditions. Therefore, the central authority () proposed by the communists for the distribution of the various tasks and their reward, would very soon find that it had undertaken a task the solution of which far exceeds the abilities of individual men."


抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Hermann Heinrich Gossen」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.